Reducing Financial Discrimination in America
By Robert E. Wright, Nef Family Chair of Political Economy, Augustana University for the ASHE/NEA Conference in Polson, MT, June 2018
America’s financial history is rife with examples of financial
exclusion, discrimination, and predation. Exclusion occurred when women or
people of certain ethnicities, races, religions, or sexual orientations were as
a group denied access to portions of the financial system. It was outlawed,
more or less, and is relatively rare today because it is costly to work around
even for the most committed bigots.
Discrimination, whereby specific individuals are denied credit,
insurance, or other financial service despite being objectively qualified for
it, is more subtle and hence difficult to detect. Sometimes, instead of
outright denial, it takes the form of higher interest or premium rates but
always for ostensibly objective reasons. Its extent is difficult to discern
statistically and real world experiments, whereby people with practically
identical qualifications but different genders, ethnicities, skins colors and
so forth apply for financial services at the same provider, cannot, for legal
reasons, go all the way to the formal application stage.
Predation is the inverse of discrimination, occurring when an
individual who objectively does not qualify for a financial service, usually a
loan, is allowed, even encouraged, to contract under the expectation of default
and a windfall for the lender. Again, pinning down exact numbers is fraught in
our messy real world, but predation certainly occurs and of course was common
in the subprime mortgage and payday lending markets of the early Third
Millennium AD. Determining the extent of predation is difficult, too, because
high rates of interest are not prima facie evidence of it, as it is costly to
make small, short term loans and of course annualizing rates can be deceptive.
Most people balk when they hear a loan has a 1,000% interest rate but when that
loan is described as costing $23 and was taken out to avoid a $50 late fee, it
suddenly seems like a mutually beneficial transaction.
Three ways of reducing financial discrimination have been tried in
the U.S. The worst approach was implemented in the 1990s, when regulators began
to encourage lenders to lower credit standards. That approach encouraged
predatory lending by granting lenders ample access to borrowers with poor or no
credit histories, few assets, and relatively little secure income. In other
words, targeting borrowers most vulnerable to predatory lenders became
acceptable, even mainstream. Lowering credit standards also encouraged mortgage
securitization and ultimately led to the subprime mortgage crisis and resultant
financial panic and global recession, the negative effects of which are still
being felt.
Lowering credit standards was the regulatory response to failed
attempts to mandate an end to financial discrimination via laws like the
Community Reinvestment Act or CRA, which, regulators had hoped, would be as
effective as outlawing outright financial exclusion had been in the 1960s.
Alas, it was much easier to enforce a law stating that banks and insurers could
not reject the applications of all women, African-Americans, Hispanics, Native
Americans and so forth than it was to cajole them into not discriminating
against individual members of those same groups. Lenders and insurers had to
have the last say in who they would lend to or insure and of course the government
itself did not want to directly enter the loan business. Various U.S. colonies
and states had tried that game and gotten burned more often than not, even when
making loans to presumably prime borrowers.
Traditionally, the U.S. had handled discrimination not with
top-down regulations like the CRA, but rather via markets. This third approach
is not a panacea for reasons I will explain later but it was more effective
than eroding standards or trying to regulate institutions that have proven
themselves both too big to fail and too big to regulate. It was called
self-help and entailed regulatory gatekeepers allowing groups that felt
discriminated against to form their own financial institutions. The logic was
that if a group that felt discriminated against was really not, if it was
composed of individuals who should not receive loans or insurance or whatever,
or if group members could indeed obtain service at existing companies, the new
institution would soon fail. That would impose a cost on the regulatory safety
net but a light one. If members of the group were actually being discriminated
against, then the new institution should succeed, thrive, grow, and so forth,
thus reducing if not ending the discrimination. Self-help, in other words, was
a market test of discrimination and a way of allowing Gary Becker’s insight
that competition destroys discrimination to work itself out in the real world.
The Lumbee Guaranty Bank, for example,
charges its borrowers a higher interest rate than the local bank run by
Euroamericans. So Dobbs Oxendine, a Lumbee entrepreneur, borrows from the
latter. The very fact that he can do so suggests that the Lumbee Guaranty Bank
may not be necessary. Regulatory approaches that rely on markets have a far
better chance of success, of actually helping those groups that regulators
purport they would like to help, than those that try to repress markets.
The self-help approach worked amazingly well throughout U.S.
history. Early in the nation’s history, commercial banks catered mostly to
wealthy merchants. When artisans, farmers, and manufacturers complained,
lawmakers allowed them to form their own commercial banks. They did, and it was
good, as the new entrants thrived and the established institutions began to
re-think their prejudices. Then philanthropists created new institutions,
called mutual savings banks, that allowed another unbanked group, the poorest
of the poor, to safely earn market returns on any pennies they were able to
save. Members of the working classes took note and, excluded from both the
savings banks by maximum deposit regulations and commercial banks, which would
not cater to consumers until the twentieth century, they gained permission from
lawmakers to form their own financial institutions, which they called building
and loans. Later, the working classes would form and join credit unions, Morris
Plan banks, and industrial banks. Their fraternal organizations competed with industrial
life insurers in the provision of low-cost burial and life insurance.
Members of the immigrant groups that streamed into America over
the course of the nineteenth century also found it difficult to gain access to established
financial institutions. In case you aren’t aware of this history, many
Americans considered Irish Catholics to be almost simian. But when they wanted
to form their own commercial and savings banks, building and loans, credit
unions, and life insurers, lawmakers allowed them to, setting a precedent
followed by all the subsequent waves of European immigrants, from the German
Forty-Eighters fleeing political persecution to Eastern Europeans seeking a
better life.
Some of those immigrants were Jews who found themselves
discriminated against on Wall Street. So they established their own investment
banks, including Kuehn Loeb and Goldman Sachs. Well after World War II, various
big investment banks, brokerages, life insurers, and investment funds were
associated with different religious groups, some Jewish, some Catholic, some
WASP. The rhetoric of free enterprise meant that any group that could put
up their own capital and/or find financial backers had the right to enter and
compete for business on any basis. There were even African-American brokerages
by the 1950s.
Blacks, Hispanics, women, and even some American Indians joined
the self-help bandwagon and formed their own banks and insurers. Black-owned
life insurers were particularly successful, as were black-owned banks where
ever African-American businesses thrived, as they did in Tulsa until the
infamous white riot there in 1921.
In 1943, Edwin Embree, a high ranking
executive in several important philanthropic foundations, summarized the state
of black financial enterprise prior to World War II as follows:
The insurance companies, which grew out of the widespread
burial and mutual societies, have flourished because of the discrimination
against Negro policyholders by the large white companies. Banks, which despite
a number of failures rank close to insurance in financial importance, have as
one of their chief reasons for existence the refusal of general banking
institutions to give credit on equal terms with others to Negro individuals and
businesses.
Self-help was less effective when levels of bigotry were high,
however, because the self-help institutions themselves were discriminated
against. In early postwar Chicago, for example, 21 lending
companies with assets of almost $8.9 million were run by African-Americans but
they found raising adequate capital “all but impossible” because “non-Negro
institutions” would not buy, or lend on the collateral of, their mortgages.
Savers therefore tended to eschew them for the higher rates or greater safety
afforded by lending institutions run by whites. At the same time in Philadelphia,
however, a black banker named Edward C. Brown leveraged his reputation for
financial wizardry to obtain loans on favorable terms from institutions run by
whites.
So some banks owned and operated by African-Americans, women,
Hispanics, and other oppressed groups did manage to survive and even thrive. And
new ones continued to form, though at a rate barely above the rate of exit, a
few from bankruptcy but most from mergers. The great merger waves that swept
the life insurance and banking industries, the latter following the
deregulation of first intra-state and then interstate branching in the final
three decades of the last century and the first decade of the present one,
greatly reduced the salience of self-help. Between 2000 and 2014, for instance,
the number of banks owned and operated by American Indians increased from 14 to
just 19 on net. Regulators apparently did not find the stagnation of self-help
problematic as they believed that the CRA and/or lowered credit standards had,
or would, virtually eliminate discrimination. They were wrong about that but
enough time has passed since its heyday that few regulators remember the historical
importance of the self-help approach.
And it hasn’t helped that de novo banking went extinct for
everybody following the Panic of 2008, when I was part of a group, led by a
wealthy paraplegic, just starting to develop a proposal for a bank to service
people facing a wide range of physical and psychological challenges. Yes, a
handi-bank for lack of a better term. Discrimination comes in many forms, which
is why we should prefer market responses. Markets, after all, are usually much
more nimble and subtle than top down regulations.
The effectiveness of self-help can also be reduced when few
members of the group being discriminated against possess the human capital, the
skills, education, and experience, needed to successfully enter banking,
insurance, or other financial services. Thankfully, commercial banking is not
rocket science. One does not need an MBA from a top tier business school to
become a good community banker. In fact, such a pedigree would probably be a
disqualification.
Actuarial work is rocket science -- almost literally as
many actuaries trained as physicists -- but actuarial and other highly
technical services can be outsourced, at least at first. Where you need members
of the group being discriminated against is in the trenches were loan and
insurance applications are received, processed, and decided. That is where
their understanding of their own group can do the most good, first by enticing
people to apply and second by providing more nuanced judgments about
applicants’ ability to repay or minimize claims.
A banker from off the Reservation, for example, may think that an
applicant’s income is too low but a fellow American Indian might realize that
the applicant has significant income that he can’t show as it may come from the
applicant’s own subsistence activities or in-kind aid from members of his clan.
An outside banker also doesn’t understand land tenure systems on Reservations
and has little incentive to, but an Indian banker would. An outside banker
won’t make a loan on a car that she can’t find an approximate market value for
on the Internet, but an Indian banker can estimate the value of a Rez car. And
so on and so forth. And similar scenarios can be imagined for every group that
can’t get loans or insurance, from members of the LBGTQ community to rednecks
to African-Americans.
None of this means that regulators should allow just anyone to
enter any financial service and completely wing it. Philanthropies and
regulators can help jumpstart self-help success by supplying start up capital
and subsidizing the education and maybe even some work experience for members
of groups underrepresented in the financial services sector and work with them
to help build their businesses. But they need to step aside at some point and
allow the bank or insurer to sink or swim on its own merits.
Recently, the Minneapolis Fed and the
Philadelphia Fed, implemented programs designed to help African-Americans and
American Indians to create their own financial institutions. Much more remains
to be done but regulators need to combat the inclinations of incumbent
financial institutions, which would rather face ineffective top-down
regulations like CRA than additional competition.
Regulators should also work to minimize business-to-business
discrimination. A bank owned and operated by American Indians or, I don’t know,
Furries, should not have to pay a higher interest rate for overnight funds than
any other bank of its size, region, and longevity. Insurers should be able to
obtain reinsurance on rational terms, and so forth.
I cannot stress enough that self-help is not a panacea. It cannot
overcome systemic racism. But it is a more market-oriented approach than top
down regulations and much less of a systemic risk than lowering application
standards. Throughout U.S. history, it frequently worked completely but even
where its success was limited we have to remember that self-help banks and
insurers still helped their customers to obtain needed financial services, even
if it was just for a few years or decades, or in just a few places. Moreover,
some groups may be able to make more headway with self-help than in the past as
bigotry and prejudice, while still lamentably powerful, are perhaps not quite
as ubiquitous as in the past. There is only one way to find out and that is for
regulatory gatekeepers to once again encourage new entry by any group that
believes it is being discriminated against.
Thank you!
No comments:
Post a Comment