Selling Slavery: Conflating Profits with Prosperity in the
Early Republic
Robert E. Wright, Augustana University, at the American
Historical Association Conference, Sheraton Denver, CO, 7 January 2017,
1:30-3:00 p.m. Governor’s Square 15
Slavery in America was often called the “Peculiar
Institution” but what is truly peculiar is the historiography of slavery. From
about 1850 until about 2010, people opposed to slavery held that slavery hurt
economic growth, defined as increased, inflation-adjusted per capita aggregate
output and measured by indices like GDP, and development, defined as the
capacity for growth and measured by various indices of literacy, education, technology,
and infrastructure. People who argued during that period that slavery aided
economic growth and development were racist, pro-slavery advocates like George Fitzhugh,
or, like Robert Fogel and Stan Engerman, they were castigated as racist, pro-slavery
advocates by various liberals and progressives.
That equilibrium made good intuitive sense because it
allowed anti-slavery thinkers to advocate abolition on both moral and economic
grounds. No tradeoff between morality and growth was necessary on either side;
either slavery was all bad or it was all good. In recent years, however, a
spate of books by Ed Baptist, Sven Beckert, Robin Blackburn, Walter Johnson,
Calvin Schermerhorn, and others has attempted to break the equilibrium by
maintaining that slavery, while a moral evil, aided, nay caused, U.S. economic growth and development. None of those authors
has been called racist because their goal is to make a case for general
reparations from taxpayers to the descendants of slaves. Such a policy, though,
would be fraught with difficulties, the most important of which is that slavery
actually hurt the overall U.S. economy.
As I show in Poverty
of Slavery: How Unfree Labor Pollutes the Economy, which Palgrave is
publishing in early March of this year, slavery creates profits for enslavers
but it does not stimulate growth or development. Most obviously, only a few
slave nations grew rich and some grew rich without, or before, becoming slave
powers. Without having to run a single regression, we therefore know that slavery
is neither a necessary nor a sufficient cause of economic growth.
Poverty of Slavery also shows that slavery could not
have aided growth or development at the margins either. That is because slavery
creates huge negative externalities, or costs not born by enslavers. So while
slavery was often profitable for enslavers, its marginal net effect on the
economy was clearly negative when the costs of controlling slaves and numerous
other negative externalities, like decreased innovation, population, and
non-slave wages, are accounted for. That holds not just for the antebellum U.S.
but for every slave society the globe over since prehistoric times. Those few slave
nations that attained wealth and development did so despite slavery, not because of it.
Without the concept of negative externalities, which
economists did not formally name until the early 20th century, identifying
the poverty induced by slavery is difficult to discern. That is why prior to
about 1850 or so abolitionists were often silent about the economic effects of
slavery. They knew that slavery was a ubiquitous institution because it was
usually profitable and feared that those profits meant that slavery stimulated growth
and development. So they remained fixated on the moral and religious aspects of
the institution, a message that many Americans did not find compelled them to
action. Early proslavery thinkers also did not calculate the negative
externalities created by slavery, yet they often downplayed the profitability
of enslaving others for rhetorical and competitive reasons, so they, too, generally
concentrated on the cultural and religious effects of enslavement.
Those who came to see the negative externalities created by
slavery became abolitionists because it removed all doubt from their minds.
Hinton Helper was the most famous of these. His Impending Crisis is basically an extended, if somewhat sloppy,
analysis of the negative externalities created by slavery. “Slavery,”
he wrote, “benefits no one but its immediate, individual owners, and them only
in a pecuniary point of view.” “Does the slaveholder, while he is enjoying his
slaves,” Helper wondered, “reflect upon the deep injury and incalculable loss
which the possession of that property inflicts upon the true interests of the
country?” Or my favorite: “Slaveholders! … You are daily engaged in the unmanly
and unpatriotic work of impoverishing the land of your birth. … Your conduct is
reprehensible, base, criminal.”
Helper was not the
first to separate profits from growth and development, nor was he the first to
point to the many costs that slaves imposed on the larger economy. In 1764,
Philadelphia merchant Nicholas Waln wrote to Richard Waln: “The
illicit Trade wch has been carryed on a long time has probably
enriched the Individual, but I believe in the Event will extremely derogate
from the Good & true Interest of the Colonies.” A few years later, a writer
in New York also noted that “a Merchant may, and often does, get rich by a
Trade that makes his Country poor.” In one of his famous state papers,
Alexander Hamilton also noted that profits and economic growth were sometimes
incompatible. In 1817, Littleton D. Teackle of Maryland noted that “merchants,
speculators, stock-jobbers and money changers … may flourish and get rich
though the country be ruined.”
The notion that the
enslavement of others was one of the activities by which a few became enriched
at the expense of the whole can be dated back to at least Jean Bodin, a
sixteenth century French philosopher, who argued that the profits created by
slaves were offset by the fear induced by the institution in both slaves and
the general population. As Bodin put it, slave societies were “always in
daunger of trouble and ruine, by the conspiracie of slaves combining themselves
together: All Histories being full of servile rebellions and warres.”
Eighteenth century German scholar Johann Gottfried Herder also clearly saw that
slavery created social costs not borne by slave masters. He attributed to
slavery the spread of syphilis and the devastation of three continents.
In the early nineteenth
century, the notion that slavery imposed large costs on non-slaveholders gained
traction in America. In 1805, Thomas Branagan of Philadelphia compared slavery
“to a large tree planted in the south, whose spreading branches extends to the
North; the poisonous fruit of that tree when ripe falls upon these states, to
the annoyance of the inhabitants, and contamination of the land which is sacred
to liberty.” George Mason had also likened slavery to a “slow Poison” and in
1832 fellow Virginian Henry Berry argued that slavery was akin to raising
tigers, something the state certainly had an interest in arresting, even if it
was “a very lucrative business.”
Virginians would not be allowed to raise “the far-famed Upas tree” (the “Tree
of Death”), he argued, even if it grew entirely on their own private land. That
same year, Charles James Faulkner said the same thing but much more directly before
the Virginia House of Delegates: “Slaves are injurious to the interests and
threaten the subversion and ruin of this Commonwealth.”
Just a year later, on
the other side of the Atlantic, Joseph Conder argued that free laborers cost
society less than slaves did because slavery encouraged “a wasteful and
deteriorating husbandry” due to its reliance on monoculture and primitive tools
as well as “contingent social evils, which demand a precautionary provision.”
“The ultimate cost of slavery,” he concluded, also included “the state
expenditure which it renders necessary in order to provide against the dangers
inseparable from the existence of a servile class.”
Such arguments could at first be dismissed as mere rhetoric
but as the years turned into decades one of the greatest natural experiments in
history, the division of the United States into free and slave slaves, helped
observers to test the negative externality hypothesis. As
early as 1824, the economies of Pennsylvania and Virginia were compared and the
former found superior. Several decades later, the economic differences between
otherwise comparable free and slave states were even more pronounced, a point
made forcefully by Cassius Clay, a Kentucky slaveholder ‘mugged by reality’ and
converted to the antislavery cause. Despite Virginia’s natural advantages over
New York, the latter exceeded the former in “the elements of National
prosperity and glory; wealth, numbers in new countries, literature, industry,
the mechanic arts, scientific agriculture, &c.” Slavery, Clay concluded,
was clearly to blame. “The twelve hundred millions of capital invested in
slaves is a dead loss to the South,” he declared, predicting, accurately, that
the free North would defeat the slave South in a civil war.
At the outset of that
war, Irish economist John Elliott Cairnes established the orthodox view that
held until about 2010:
Those who are acquainted
with the elementary principles which govern the distribution of wealth, know
that the profits of capitalists may be increased by the same process by which
the gross revenue of a country is diminished, and that therefore the community
as a whole may be impoverished through the very same means by which a portion
of its number is enriched. The economic success of slavery, therefore, is
perfectly consistent with the supposition that it is prejudicial to the material
well-being of the country where it is established.
Before closing, I need to make clear that the issue of
externalities and the economic effects of slavery is not a merely academic one.
In case you haven’t heard, slavery did not end in the nineteenth century, it
merely changed form, into debt peonage, bonded labor, sex trafficking, child
soldiers, and myriad other forms. Although unfree laborers compose a much
smaller portion of the global work force than ever before, in absolute numbers
they are now more numerous, between 30 and 45 million by common estimates, than
at any time in history. The notion that slavery can jumpstart economies can,
and has, been used to justify enslaving people today. Claims that Britain and
the U.S. grew rich due to slavery have emboldened those in developing nations
to ignore international anti-trafficking protocols on the supposition that it
is not fair for the rich nations to prevent poor nations from catching up economically
by outlawing a key growth driver. What this paper, and Poverty of Slavery, re-establish is that slavery is not just
immoral, it is bad economics because any economic benefit produced by
enslavers’ marginal profits, the profits earned above and beyond what would
have been earned using a less coercive labor regime, is more than wiped out by
the societal costs created when people are forced to work against their will.
This in no way diminishes the sacrifices of African-American slaves or indeed
any other group enslaved in the past, which, by the way, would include most
people alive today. It does, however, suggest that general reparations for
slavery are not merited and that the descendants of slaves should look to the
profits created by their ancestors for recompense.
Thank you.
No comments:
Post a Comment